| Peer-Reviewed

Oil Shocks and Macroeconomic Effects of Occasionally Binding Constraint on External Reserves of CEMAC

Received: 28 October 2019    Accepted: 22 November 2019    Published: 2 December 2019
Views:       Downloads:
Abstract

This paper investigates the macroeconomic effects of Central African States Bank (BEAC) commitment to ensure its nominal anchoring when the underlying external reserves constraint occurs after an oil shock. Indeed, the current monetary agreements place external reserves at the heart of the cooperation between BEAC and the French Treasury, and their fluctuations are the main risks indicators to the durability of the cooperation between these two institutions: a system described as pegged to reserves which neither fully resembles a fixed exchange rate regime or a flexible exchange rate regime, much less an intermediate regime. To this end, there is a need to monitor their ability to cover a proportion of the central bank's liabilities in the short run by tithing the monetary conditions, in order to avoid drastic adjustment measures as devaluation. Therefore, as a result of the fall of these reserves below their long run threshold, the central bank essentially focused on their recovery. Our framework is a Markov-switching approach of the Smets and Wouters textbook model were we have modelled the dynamics of external reserves from the balance of payments identity and the simplified balance sheet of the central bank. The monetary policy rule is also augmented by the gap of reserves to their long run trend. Two scenarios are subsequently evaluated namely, a variation of the probability of occurrence of the constraint while maintaining that of leaving or, conversely, a variation of the probability of exit from the constraint by assuming that its occurrence is fixed. The results obtained show that at the approach of the constraint and in the presence of an oil shock, the behaviour of the central bank induces many undesired effects such as the fall in consumption, investment and production. Conversely, when the probability of exit from the constraint is high, the central bank adopts a somewhat passive behaviour, with a late reaction that makes the imbalances continue. Following the fact that (i) export revenue of the region are mainly composed of oil resources (84%), (ii) imports are rigid and, (iii) the oil price cannot be under control of CEMAC countries for competitiveness purpose, the paper highlights the need for permanent monetary discipline alongside economic diversification.

Published in International Journal of Business and Economics Research (Volume 8, Issue 6)
DOI 10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23
Page(s) 422-438
Creative Commons

This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, provided the original work is properly cited.

Copyright

Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Science Publishing Group

Keywords

Occasionally Binding Constraint, External Reserves, Markov-Switching DSGE, Macroeconomics Effects

References
[1] Direction de la Recherche (2017), “Les déterminants de la dynamique des réserves de change dans la CEMAC de janvier 2016 à septembre 2017”, Note d’Etude.
[2] Mvondo T. (2018), “La pertinence du TIAO comme instrument de politique monétaire de la BEAC: Fondements théoriques et évaluation empirique”, BEAC Working Paper.
[3] Taylor J. B. (1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice”, Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, December 1993b, 39, pp. 195--214.
[4] Lucas R. J. (1976), “Econometric policy evaluation: A critique”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1 (1), 19–46.
[5] Binning A., and Maih J. (2017), “Modelling Occasionally Binding Constraints Using Regime-Switching”, Norges Bank Research Working Paper.
[6] Brzoza-Brzezina M., Kolasa M., and Makarski K. (2015), “A penalty function approach to occasionally binding credit constraints”. Economic Modelling, 51 (C), 315–327.
[7] Gertler M. and Karadi P. (2011), “A model of unconventional monetary policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics 58.1, pp. 17–34.
[8] Christiano L., Rostagno M. and Motto R. (2010), “Financial factors in economic fluctuations”, Working Paper Series 1192. European Central Bank.
[9] Kiyotaki N. and Moore J. (2012), “Liquidity, Business Cycles, and Monetary Policy”, NBER Working Papers 17934. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
[10] Shi S. (2015), “Liquidity, assets and business cycles”, Journal of Monetary Economics 70.0, pp. 116–132.
[11] Bigio S. (2017), “Liquidity shocks and the business cycle: What next”, European Economic Review, Elsevier, Vol. 97 (C), pp. 108-130.
[12] Kiyotaki N. and Moore J. (1997), “Credit Cycles”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 105, n°2.
[13] Iacoviello M. (2005), “House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle”, American Economic Revue, 95 (3), 739–764.
[14] Liu Z., P. Wang and T. Zha (2013), “Land-price dynamics and macroeconomic fluctuations”, Econometrica 81 (3), 1147–1184.
[15] Blanchard O. J., and Khan C. M. (1980), “The Solution of Linear Difference Models Under Rational Expectations”, Econometrica, Vol. 48, N° 5 (July, 1980).
[16] Den Haan W. J. and De Wind J. (2012), “Nonlinear and stable perturbation-based approximations”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 36 (10), 1477–1497.
[17] Kim J. and Ruge-Murcia F. J. (2011), “Monetary policy when wages are downwardly rigid: Friedman meets Tobin”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35 (12), 2064–2077.
[18] Holden T. and Paetz M. (2012), “Efficient Simulation of DSGE Models with Inequality Constraints”, Quantitative Macroeconomics Working Papers 21207b, Hamburg University, Department of Economics.
[19] Lindé J., Smets F., and Wouters R. (2016), “Challenges for Central Banks’ Macro Models”, Working Paper Series 323, Sveriges Riksbank (Central Bank of Sweden).
[20] Bianchi F. and Melosi L. (2014), “Escaping the Great Recession”. NBER Working Papers 20238, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
[21] Chen H. (2014), “Assessing the effects of the zero-interest-rate policy through the lens of a regime-switching dsge model”. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2014-38, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).
[22] Binning, A. and Maih, J. (2016), “Implementing the Zero Lower Bound in an Estimated Regime Switching DSGE model”. Working Paper 2016/3, Norges Bank.
[23] Benigno G., Foerester A., Otrok C., Rebucci A., and Young E. R. (2017), “Estimating macroeconomic models of financial crisis: An Endogenous Regime Switching Approach”. 2017 Meetings Papers 572 Society for Economic Dynamics.
[24] Smets F. et Wouters R. (2003), “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area”, Journal of the European Economic Association, September 2003 1 (5): 1123-1175.
[25] Tinel, B. (2016), “Le fonctionnement des comptes d’opérations et leur rôle dans les relations entre la France et les pays africains”, Document de Travail du Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne.
[26] Guillaumont, S. J. et P. Guillaumont (2017), “Quel avenir pour les francs CFA? ” Document de Travail du FERDI.
[27] Nubukpo, K. (2007), Politique monétaire et servitude volontaire: la gestion du franc CFA par la Banque Centrale des Etats de l’Afrique de l’Ouest (BCEAO) ”, Politique Africaine n°105, mars 2007, Karthala, Paris, pp. 70-82.
[28] Diop, I. T., F. Gueye et A. A. Mbaye (2017), “Sortie des pays africains de la zone Franc: entre le mythe et la réalité, Transformations”, Revue Interventions économiques, Mars 2017.
[29] Gomba E. B., Kenkouo G. A., Mvondo E. T., Nafe Daba (2017), “Chocs et fluctuations macroéconomiques au Cameroun”, BEAC Working Paper.
[30] Mvondo T. (2019), “Réformes financières et formation des taux d’intérêt en Afrique Centrale: une approche à travers le modèle DSGE”, Revue Interventions économiques, N° 61.
[31] De Zamaroczy M., Fleuriet et V., J. Gijon (2018), “Gestion des réserves internationales de la CEMAC: une nouvelle approche à moyen terme”, Fonds Monétaire International.
[32] Mundell R. (1961), “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas”, American Economic Review, 51, 1961.
[33] Mc Kinnon R. I. (1963), “Optimum Currency areas”, American Economic Review.
[34] Kenen P. B. (1969), “The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An eclectic View in R. A. Mundell and Swoboda, A. K.,” (eds) Monetary Problems of the International Economy, pp 41-60 University of Chicago Press.
[35] Elhiraika A. et Ndikumana L. (2009), “L’Accumulation de réserves dans les pays africains: sources, motivations et effets”, Actes de la Conférence économique africaine, Addis Abeba (Ethiopie) du 15 au 17 novembre 2007.
[36] Mohanty M. and Turner P. (2006), “Foreign exchange reserve accumulation in emerging markets: what are the domestic implications?” BIS Quarterly Review.
[37] Calvo G. A. (1983), “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework”, Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 383–98.
[38] Dixit A. K and Stiglitz J. E. (1977), “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity”, American Economic Review, Vol. 67 N°3 (June 1977), pp. 297-308.
[39] Mvondo T. (2011), “L’hypothèse de neutralité monétaire: une application en Zone Franc”, Thèse pour le Doctorat en Sciences économiques, Université de Nancy 2.
[40] Ngomba Bodi F. G. et Onomo Betsama J. (2018), “Analyse du multiplicateur monétaire en Zone CEMAC: Evolution, stabilité et prévision”, BEAC Working Paper.
[41] Mvondo E. T. (2016), “Formation des habitudes et consommation agrégée dans la CEMAC”, BEAC Working Paper.
[42] Berg A., Portillo R., Yang S. and Zanna L. (2012), “Public Investment in Resource-Abundant Developing Countries”, IMF Working Paper.
[43] Bikaï J. L., et Mbohou Mama M. (2016), “Une fonction de réaction pour la Banque des Etats de l’Afrique Centrale dans un contexte de dominance budgétaire”, BEAC Working Paper.
[44] Mounkala E. U., Keungne L. S. and Munkam M. A. (2016), “Optimalité de la politique monétaire de la BEAC depuis 2001”, BEAC Working Paper.
Cite This Article
  • APA Style

    Thierry Mvondo. (2019). Oil Shocks and Macroeconomic Effects of Occasionally Binding Constraint on External Reserves of CEMAC. International Journal of Business and Economics Research, 8(6), 422-438. https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23

    Copy | Download

    ACS Style

    Thierry Mvondo. Oil Shocks and Macroeconomic Effects of Occasionally Binding Constraint on External Reserves of CEMAC. Int. J. Bus. Econ. Res. 2019, 8(6), 422-438. doi: 10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23

    Copy | Download

    AMA Style

    Thierry Mvondo. Oil Shocks and Macroeconomic Effects of Occasionally Binding Constraint on External Reserves of CEMAC. Int J Bus Econ Res. 2019;8(6):422-438. doi: 10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23

    Copy | Download

  • @article{10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23,
      author = {Thierry Mvondo},
      title = {Oil Shocks and Macroeconomic Effects of Occasionally Binding Constraint on External Reserves of CEMAC},
      journal = {International Journal of Business and Economics Research},
      volume = {8},
      number = {6},
      pages = {422-438},
      doi = {10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23},
      url = {https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23},
      eprint = {https://article.sciencepublishinggroup.com/pdf/10.11648.j.ijber.20190806.23},
      abstract = {This paper investigates the macroeconomic effects of Central African States Bank (BEAC) commitment to ensure its nominal anchoring when the underlying external reserves constraint occurs after an oil shock. Indeed, the current monetary agreements place external reserves at the heart of the cooperation between BEAC and the French Treasury, and their fluctuations are the main risks indicators to the durability of the cooperation between these two institutions: a system described as pegged to reserves which neither fully resembles a fixed exchange rate regime or a flexible exchange rate regime, much less an intermediate regime. To this end, there is a need to monitor their ability to cover a proportion of the central bank's liabilities in the short run by tithing the monetary conditions, in order to avoid drastic adjustment measures as devaluation. Therefore, as a result of the fall of these reserves below their long run threshold, the central bank essentially focused on their recovery. Our framework is a Markov-switching approach of the Smets and Wouters textbook model were we have modelled the dynamics of external reserves from the balance of payments identity and the simplified balance sheet of the central bank. The monetary policy rule is also augmented by the gap of reserves to their long run trend. Two scenarios are subsequently evaluated namely, a variation of the probability of occurrence of the constraint while maintaining that of leaving or, conversely, a variation of the probability of exit from the constraint by assuming that its occurrence is fixed. The results obtained show that at the approach of the constraint and in the presence of an oil shock, the behaviour of the central bank induces many undesired effects such as the fall in consumption, investment and production. Conversely, when the probability of exit from the constraint is high, the central bank adopts a somewhat passive behaviour, with a late reaction that makes the imbalances continue. Following the fact that (i) export revenue of the region are mainly composed of oil resources (84%), (ii) imports are rigid and, (iii) the oil price cannot be under control of CEMAC countries for competitiveness purpose, the paper highlights the need for permanent monetary discipline alongside economic diversification.},
     year = {2019}
    }
    

    Copy | Download

  • TY  - JOUR
    T1  - Oil Shocks and Macroeconomic Effects of Occasionally Binding Constraint on External Reserves of CEMAC
    AU  - Thierry Mvondo
    Y1  - 2019/12/02
    PY  - 2019
    N1  - https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23
    DO  - 10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23
    T2  - International Journal of Business and Economics Research
    JF  - International Journal of Business and Economics Research
    JO  - International Journal of Business and Economics Research
    SP  - 422
    EP  - 438
    PB  - Science Publishing Group
    SN  - 2328-756X
    UR  - https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijber.20190806.23
    AB  - This paper investigates the macroeconomic effects of Central African States Bank (BEAC) commitment to ensure its nominal anchoring when the underlying external reserves constraint occurs after an oil shock. Indeed, the current monetary agreements place external reserves at the heart of the cooperation between BEAC and the French Treasury, and their fluctuations are the main risks indicators to the durability of the cooperation between these two institutions: a system described as pegged to reserves which neither fully resembles a fixed exchange rate regime or a flexible exchange rate regime, much less an intermediate regime. To this end, there is a need to monitor their ability to cover a proportion of the central bank's liabilities in the short run by tithing the monetary conditions, in order to avoid drastic adjustment measures as devaluation. Therefore, as a result of the fall of these reserves below their long run threshold, the central bank essentially focused on their recovery. Our framework is a Markov-switching approach of the Smets and Wouters textbook model were we have modelled the dynamics of external reserves from the balance of payments identity and the simplified balance sheet of the central bank. The monetary policy rule is also augmented by the gap of reserves to their long run trend. Two scenarios are subsequently evaluated namely, a variation of the probability of occurrence of the constraint while maintaining that of leaving or, conversely, a variation of the probability of exit from the constraint by assuming that its occurrence is fixed. The results obtained show that at the approach of the constraint and in the presence of an oil shock, the behaviour of the central bank induces many undesired effects such as the fall in consumption, investment and production. Conversely, when the probability of exit from the constraint is high, the central bank adopts a somewhat passive behaviour, with a late reaction that makes the imbalances continue. Following the fact that (i) export revenue of the region are mainly composed of oil resources (84%), (ii) imports are rigid and, (iii) the oil price cannot be under control of CEMAC countries for competitiveness purpose, the paper highlights the need for permanent monetary discipline alongside economic diversification.
    VL  - 8
    IS  - 6
    ER  - 

    Copy | Download

Author Information
  • Department of Studies, Research and Statistics, Central African States Bank, Yaoundé, Cameroon

  • Sections